According
to studies, the health benefit exists already from a moderate intensity
of physical activity – it is sufficient to burn just 150 calories a
day, or 1000 calories a week - and the level of benefit is directly and
positively correlated with the intensity, frequency and duration of
physical activity. The
United States Department of Health and Human Services conclude that
regular physical activity and, possibly, caloric restriction, seem to be
the only lifestyle factors which can favourably influence a wide range
of physiological systems and chronic disease risk factors as well as
mental health and social integration. Despite large genetic differences,
it appears that physical activity may be the key that differentiates
between those who do and do not experience successful aging. The
CMA (cost minimisation analysis) shows that one can expect a physically
active adult to incur $117,000 less in disease-related costs compared
to a sedentary individual. If all Israeli 40yr olds met recommended
levels this would translate to a $9.5 billion saving over the lifetime
of the cohort. If we assume that parameters are largely unchanged for a
cohort aged 20-65 years we can multiply these figures by the over 3,2
million adults in Israel and see a potential annual saving of close to
$10 billion. Even if only 1% becomes active one could invest $90 million
a year and still realise a saving. The CUA then calculates at what
levels of population adherence to PA recommendations and at what level
of societal investment enabling PA would be cost-effective. המחקר
בונה שני מודלים של ניתוח באמצעות עץ החלטות מבוסס על קוהורט מבוגרים
בריאים בני 40 שנה: Cost-minimisation analysis (CMA) וגם Cost-utility
analysis (CUA) . המודלים מורכבים מנתונים אשר נאספו מן הספרות המקומית
והבינלאומית על עלויות המחלה , התחלואה, איכות חיים והמידה שבה פעילות
גופנית משפיעה על גורמים אלה. עולה כי ניתן להפחית כ 117,000 $ מההוצאות
הרפואיות אצל אדם פעיל, לעומת אדם לא פעיל. אם כל הקוהורט בארץ היה מגיע
לרמות המומלצות של פ"ג הרי יכולנו לצפות לחיסכון בסך 9.5 מיליארד דולר
אמריקאי לאורך חייו של הקוהורט. . אם מניחים שפרמטרים אלה תקפים לקוהורט
בני 20-65 ומכפילים את המספרים באוכלוסיית ישראל מגיעים לחיסכון שנתי של כ
10 $ מיליארד. זה אומר שאפילו אם רק 1% נהיים פעילים ניתן להשקיע כ-90 $
מיליון לשנה ולראות חיסכון. In
1982 British epidemiologist Jeremy Morris defined physical activity as
―today‘s best buy of public health‖. The aim of this thesis is to submit
that claim to economic analysis. 3.3. Economic evaluations of physical activity The
quality adjusted life year (QALY) combines quality and quantity of
life, with one QALY being equivalent to one life year spent in full
health. QALY‘s suffer from a number of limitations but they still
currently provide the best methodology available for comparing outcomes
from different health care interventions. Outcomes
of CUA are therefore expressed as quantity (duration) of health status
multiplied by the quality of life (utility) of that health status. An
intervention is considered to cost-effective if it costs less and
generates more QALYs than the standard treatment. This is called
dominance. It may also be judged to be cost-effective if the incremental
cost-effectiveness ratio (ICER) falls below a certain threshold. The
incremental cost-effectiveness ratio is calculated as the estimated
difference in cost between the competing interventions/treatment divided
by the difference in QALY's gained. A QALY of $50,000/QALY gained has
historically been deemed an acceptable threshold but today there is
evidence supporting thresholds of $100,000 - $300,00 per QALY gained
(Ubel et al 2003, Braithwaite et al 2008). This is notwithstanding
debate on the value of any threshold at all (Weinstein, 2008). In order
to make the strongest case possible for the promotion of physical
activity, this dissertation uses the conservative $50,000 threshold. 4. Thesis Goals and Objectives Goal To
calculate medical cost reduction engendered by physical activity on an
individual level and, based thereon, to infer threshold parameter values
in terms of cost and efficiency whereby investing in interventions for
the promotion of physical activity on a population level is
cost-effective. General Objective Use
a decision-tree analysis model to determine the absolute savings
expected from a physically active compared to a sedentary individual and
thereafter to establish the cost-effectiveness of investing in
promoting physical activity versus a laissez-faire strategy for a cohort
of healthy adults aged 40. The measures of the effectiveness of physical activity are: 1. Reductions in disease incidence. 2. Gains in life expectancy. 3. Gains in quality of life. Notes: The model structure does not allow for all diseases prevented or ameliorated by physical activity to be included. Conditions included in the decision tree are: Coronary Heart Disease Cerebrovascular Attacks Type 2 Diabetes Mellitus Colon Cancer Breast cancer (for women) Dementia Musculoskeletal disorders (arthritis and hip fracture) Obesity was excluded
from the model due to the conflation of cause and effect when dealing
with physical inactivity. There is much overlap between them and, in
most cases, synergism of their effects on other conditions thereby
complicating the model. Results
of the CUA are expressed as an incremental cost-effectiveness ratio
(ICER), that is, the ratio of change in costs to the change in effects.
This represents the additional cost of one unit of outcome gained a
healthcare intervention or strategy, when compared to its comparator.
The formula is represented thus: ICER = (COSTnew strategy – COSTcurrent practice) / (EFFECTnew strategy – EFFECTcurrent practice) Quality
Adjusted Life Year‘s (QALY‘s) are calculated by multiplying years lived
with a condition by the utility of that condition. For a cohort of
healthy 40yr olds a combination of healthy life expectancy and life
expectancy with disease is necessary. It was assumed that the utility of
life before disease onset is 1.0 such that overall QALY‘s can be
expressed as: (Years between age 40 and disease onset * 1) + (Life expectancy at diagnosis * disease-specific utility) For
example: Life expectancy at diagnosis for Dementia is 6 years, utility
ranges from 0.14 – 0.73 and "up" ranges from 1.0 – 2.0. If one was to
take the upper ranges the resultant life expectancy is 6 * 0.73 * 2 =
8.76 which is higher than life expectancy at diagnosis. The formula was
therefore modified to take the lower of life expectancy at diagnosis and
the utility adjusted life expectancy at diagnosis. 6.1. Cost-minimisation analysis 6.1.1. CMA Base case The
median life-time saving in health costs achieved by becoming physically
active at age 40 is close to $120,000 with gain of 3.1 Quality adjusted
life-years. Assuming a life expectancy of 40 years (39.39 based on
United States 2004 Social Security Administration data and 39.81 based
on Israeli 2000 Central Bureau of Statistics data) this equates to a
saving of $3,000 per active vs. inactive person each year. One
can spend just $150 per person in the cohort, assuming that only 5%
become physically active, multiplied by a population of 80,000 (Israeli
Central Bureau of Statistics, 2008) this allows for an annual investment
of $12 million per year to reap the benefits of physical activity and
still have an overall zero cost to society. 6.2.2. CUA one-way sensitivity analyses As
in the cost-minimisation analysis, disease probabilities, costs and
utilities were not significant deciding factors as identical parameters
were used in all arms of the model. Important potential differences were
assessed as: The cost of Enabling The proportion of people being physically active under each scenario The proportion of each sex out of the active population The degree to which physical activity increases life expectancy and quality The degree to which PA decreases probability of disease The degree to which PA decreases disease cost Cost of Enabling For
lifetime costs of enabling ranging until approximately $5,000 per
person the Enabling option is dominant. Up until $7,500 per person, per
lifetime the Enabling option still remains below the $50,000/QALY mark,
increasing to over $90,000/QALY at $50,000. If
in 2008 there were 82,000 Israelis aged 40 (Central Bureau of
Statistics), over US$400 million could be spent on promoting physical
activity and still yield a net cost saving while improving the health
status of this cohort. If one is prepared to spend $50,000 per QALY
gained this would entail an investment of close to USD1 billion over the
lifetime of this cohort or $25 million per year (undiscounted). 7. Discussion This
paper reinforces current knowledge regarding the benefits of physical
activity. A single person can save close to $120,000 in health costs
over a lifetime or $3,000 a year, by initiating this lifestyle change.
If we assume that parameters are largely unchanged for a cohort aged
20-65 years we can multiply these figures by the over 3.2 million adults
in Israel and see a potential annual saving of close to $10 billion.
Even if only 1% becomes active one could invest $90 million a year and
still realise a saving. This is keeping in mind that savings are
underestimated as many conditions are not included in the model and a
person can suffer from more than one chronic disease. A ―back-of-the
envelope‖ calculation (see Appendix H) which ignores these constraints
and shows a per-person saving of closer to $200,000 – albeit not an
order of magnitude greater but still important, particularly since it
still excludes conditions for which at least one parameter was missing
and it does not take into consideration evidence that disease management
is cheaper for physically active people. As
can be seen, the model makes a strong case for facilitating physical
activity in a cohort of healthy 40yr olds. Differences in benefits and
cost-benefit ratios between the "Enabling" and "Laissez-faire" arms were
highly significant with p ≈ 0.. In the base case, using mean parameter
values, promoting physical activity costs less than $600 per QALY
gained, 50% of all iterations resulted in Enabling being both less
costly and more beneficial (dominant) compared to Laissez-faire. The
incremental cost-effectiveness ratio is less than $10,000 making
investing in PA far below even the most stringent willing-to-pay
threshold in use today. The model does prove to be sensitive to
variation in key model parameters such as cost of intervention, its
effectiveness, baseline active population as well as degree of disease
risk and cost reduction. Change in utility and proportion of females
were not significant deciding factors. Annemans
and others have shown that the results would be even more dramatic for
older populations and those already at risk of chronic disease
(hyperlipidaemia, hypertension, metabolic syndrome) as well as showing
benefit for younger, healthier cohorts as well. These results are largely compatible with results from similar studies: Annemans
et al report a narrower but similar ICER‘s range of €2,000-15,000/QALY
gained ($1500 - $11,000 based on mid-2007 exchange rate) for physical
activity versus inactivity study. This difference can be attributed
partly to a more limited condition set which would tend to reduce the
uncertainty in the model and partly to use of a Markov model which
allows for annual changes in risk as well as discounting. The
NICE cost-effectiveness analysis (2006) and Cobiac et al (2009), on the
other hand, reported more favourable results. However, Cobiac et al
assigned greater health benefits accruing from PA than those used in
this model. Furthermore, intervention costs in the NICE study are low
(maximum $544 per participant) and are accrued on an individual basis
instead of a population-wide basis. The Cobiac study included both
individual-based as well as population-based programmes which would also
tend to decrease intervention costs. Lastly, both of these studies they
measured effectiveness in terms of change in average community physical
activity levels. This allows for the accumulation of benefits to
sedentary people becoming inadequately active as well as inadequately
active people becoming more active whereas this dissertation, like
Annemans et al, calculates intervention effectiveness in terms of
percentage of the sedentary population becoming adequately active. It
is hoped that the results of this study add to the growing literature
giving weight to arguments that will convince policy-makers that
investing in a national programme to promote physical activity is a
worthwhile use of public funds as it has proved to be cost-effective in
most scenarios and may even show to be cost-saving. Source: hadassah-med.com |
Sustainability.org.il > תחבורת אופניים >